http://www.geocities.com/CapitolHill/3303/globimp.htm
Consultado junio 10 de 2000
Globalisation
and Imperialism
The theses Crisis and Imperialism which were
presented and approved by our last Congress (1983) outline the possible
outcomes of the economic crisis which had broken out in the early 70s: The
tendency is clear: we are not witnessing a conjunctural crisis which can be
resolved in a more or less greater period of time, but a permanent economic
crisis the epilogue to which can only be a new world conflict.
If we take the breakdown of the Bretton Woods
Agreement as the signal for the end of the upswing in the accumulation cycle
which opened after the 2nd World War, the crisis has now lasted a full 26 years
without the third world conflict having exploded. Obviously, having identified
the crisis as a cyclical one and not a specific short-lived storm, the prospect
of war remains valid throughout the duration of the crisis. However, this does
not exclude the possibility of some discepancy between the expected and actual
turn of events. Neither should it be used as an excuse for us to bury our heads
in the sand while we await the predicted outcome almost as if it were a
prophecy. That would mean abandoning dialectical materialism only to produce
the most banal and formal dialectic: a method which is not ours and which we
freely leave to the crowd of mechanical marxists, unfortunately of whom there
are all too many amongst the communist left.
All the evidence suggests that the destruction
of excess capital - which stems from the crisis of over-accumulation - remains
the only solution to the crisis open to the bourgeoisie, the only way that
would allow capital to pass from this accumulation cycle to another. There can
be no doubt about this. As we have demonstrated many times, the entire marxist
theory of crisis has been amply confirmed by events in recent years. There is
thus nothing new to invent or discover, but rather it is necessary to pause and
reflect on all those processes which up to now have allowed the crisis to
follow a course which in many respects has been unexpected. In one sense this
is a question of aspects of capitalism which have already been dealt with by
the marxist critique, aspects, however, which have never before manifested
themselves so clearly or had the central importance of today.
From this standpoint let's leave aside the
implosion of the Soviet Empire which, even if it constitutes one of the
essential reasons for the absence of the third world conflict, is something our
party has subjected to a detailed marxist analysis in recent years. Here we
will concentrate on powerful forces which have emerged recently and which are
more strictly linked to the economic and financial management of the crisis
since they are a prelude to changes in the whole relationship between capital
and labour and affect prospects for the revival of the class struggle.
In his examination of the law of the falling
rate of profit Marx had already shown how this tendency leads to the
internationalisation of capital. However, only the modern technological
revolution has allowed this tendency to be fully realised by pushing forward
the process of globalisation of the economy, a process bourgeois propaganda
presents as the cure for all the world's ills, the new Eldorado for which no
sacrifice is too much.
Industrial Globalisation
By contrast with previous technology, the
introduction of microelectronics has not resulted in the birth of new sectors
of production although it has brought both an absolute and a relative
destruction of a great many jobs. For the first time in the history of modern
capitalism a new technological stage - even after a fairly long crisis - has
not brought a corresponding widening of the productive base which, as well as
increasing the productivity of labour power, would also allow a quantitative
growth in the productive labour force. In fact the new technologies based on
microelectronics have essentially replaced manpower but, contrary to
expectations, have not given rise to new sectors of production. The result is
that the mechanism for compensating the fall in the rate of profit no longer
functions properly Instead it has given way to an absolute and relative
increase in surplus value extracted from a permanently contracting labour
force. This, in turn, has triggered a powerful drive towards an absolute
increase in surplus value via an extension of the working day as well as a
relative increase by upping exploitation to a level unprecedented for this
century. The result is a permanent pressure towards the devaluation of labour
power and a profound change in the labour market with a new division of labour
on a planetary level.
The telecommunications revolution and the
subsequent simplification of the work process which accompanies automation have
made it possible to transfer important segments of production to areas with
extremely low labour costs whilst using increasingly less qualified and less
costly manpower in what is an overall more complex production process. Apart
from the devaluation of labour power the result is a generalised wage structure
which is extremely flexible and which allows companies to regulate manpower and
the price they pay for it according to the fluctuations of the market. The
collective wage agreement, valued by the international bourgeoisie after the
2nd World War - particularly in the USA - because it guaranteed the stability
needed for monopoly planning has now been superseded. In its place a sort of
system of individual contracts is daily becoming the norm. The aim is to remove
any obstacle which might prevent the lowering of the price of labour power in a
situation where demand is far weaker than supply. The tendency is so powerful
that now even indirect wages - what were commonly regarded as rights acquired
for ever - are under attack: e.g. the dismantling of social insurance schemes
against old age (pensions).
In one sense a permanent lowering of the value
of labour power is an excellent substitute for the lack of compensation for the
falling rate of profit from increased numbers of workers being employed in
production. However, this also means an accentuation of the very same
contradiction because it encourages investment in substitutes for manpower. Thus
capitalist restructuring and reorganisation takes on an increasingly wide
dimension. In many sectors the relative and absolute decline in manpower has
led to a fall in global demand and poses an enormous marketing problem for all
the biggest producers. As individual national markets become more and more
restricted the international market becomes more important and bitter,
implacable struggles ensue. Finding the competitive edge thus becomes the
imperative which defines the strategic goals of all the major indusrialised
countries. But greater competitiveness means even more automation, more
automation means a further increase in constant capital and an absolute and
relative decline in variable capital, by which means the contradictions that
lead to the fall in the rate of profit tend to reaffirm themselves on an even
broader level and the tendency towards globalisation is further accelerated. There
is also, however, an even more important consequence: the amount of capital
which no longer finds an adequate return through the normal productive process
and shifts over to financial speculation.
Financial Globalisation
Every day $1,300bn move at the speed of light
from one part of the world to another in search of profit. To get an idea of
the scale of this mass of capital it's enough to know that the central banks of
all the OECD countries put together have no more than $350bn at their disposal.
Out of the world's top ten companies the first five are now finance companies
with the largest US and Japanese pension funds holding special place. Only ten
years ago the great industrial giants were safely in this top position.
Ever since the abandonment of Bretton Woods the
financial market has been extended until now there are more innovations in
financial 'services' than in the industrial sphere. In particular the creation
of the currency options market in the US in 1982 - as a result of an apposite
law (the Future Trading Act) - brought a sudden disruption to the currency
market. The creation of these new products means that the great financial
groups can now determine the amount of currency in circulation and thus
exercise the kind of control hitherto the exclusive preserve of states and
their corresponding central banks. Thanks to the hold they have over the volume
of money the whole process of international price formation is in their hands,
or rather in the hands of a limited number of investment houses, banks and
pension funds. As a result the so-called 'real economy' is overwhelmed by the
sort of returns made by finance capital and the share of surplus value destined
for speculation is continually increasing.
Until the Eighties financial speculation was
primarily directed at oscillations in the price of commodities. Now it is
directed at currency fluctuations. Contrary to the boast of governments who are
claiming the credit, the fall in the rate of inflation over recent years in the
main industrial countries is the result of speculation moving away from
commodity markets to the currency markets.
Currencies are symbolic units and can therefore
be moved around extremely swiftly from one part of the world to another, in the
process determining the collapse or vertiginous rise in the quoted price of a
particular coinage in a matter of seconds. It is easy for those who control
finance capital to intervene in the exchange quotations and gain a consistent
extra-profit. This, however, is increasingly a matter of shifting surplus value
from one capital to another and not the creation of additional value. Thus the
discrepancy between the value of money and the real value of goods produced is
permanent and is expressed in inflation which - even though it is reduced - has
been transferred from the price of commodities to currency prices and
specifically from strong currencies to the weakest. In fact this is a
problem-free way for the strongest currencies - or rather the biggest capitals
- to appropriate a share of surplus value without dirtying their hands with the
production of commodities. More generally, the whole process of wealth
distribution is gradually dictated by this movement so that an ever greater
share of surplus value is absorbed by financial receipts. Meanwhile the
international proletariat is daily called on to tighten its belt in order to
save the 'national economy' from the attacks of the speculators and calm down
the so-called markets - whose workings now have the same authority as the
decisions of the Pope: infallible and final.
In reality parasitic appropriation has become
the predominant mode of appropriation of surplus value and the domination of
the rentier, described by Lenin, has never been so total and articulate as in
our time.
The Single Ruling Idea
Apart from rare exceptions, bourgeois
economists, intellectuals and politicians view globalisation as the definitive
triumph of free competition over the world market. With deafening insistence
they maintain that the power of globalisation to bring about a single market on
a planetary scale will mean that free competition knows no limits and will
finally have reached the state of perfect competition described in the
textbooks - where economic equilibrium is determined 'naturally' by the free
play of supply and demand. And because the struggle to reach such equilibrium
excludes the least competitive firms, globalisation of the economy will also
mean the triumph of rationality and efficiency, of democracy and prosperity.
With this will come the best allocation of
resources and the best distribution of wealth, obviously also including wages. The
ideology of laissez faire enjoys unquestioned domination. It is invoked continually
to suport the liberalisation of this or that sector, the privatisation of this
or that enterprise, the abolition of any obstacle that could possibly limit the
movement of capital, of every kind of social protection (Welfare Reform) and of
any rule which might limit the exploitation of the labour force. This has been
defined by Ignacio Ramonet, editor of Le Monde Diplomatique, as the single
dominant idea and he is not wrong. It is impossible to voice any objection. You
don't have to be a marxist to be considered beyond the pale or treated as a
has-been from a now buried past: it's enough to mention Keynes for the fury of
neo-liberalism to be unleashed. However it is only in appearance that
neo-liberalism upholds the ideology of laissez-faire. The world has changed too
much for anyone to seriously compare Silicon Valley with Manchester [of the
early 19th century, trans.] and a steam-powered loom with one controlled
digitally. In reality the dominant ideology today is the ideology of a monopoly
capitalism which has reached its highest phase.
Liberalisation of markets by, for
example, abolishing existing rules and regulations and removing any obstacle
which impedes the movement of capital, has become a vital necessity for the
survival of the system because without it the gigantic processes of
concentration and centralisation of capital that globalisation implies would
not be possible.(resaltado A.Romero) A firm needs to span at least a continent in order to exist on the
global market; otherwise it is not competitive. For example a firm such as Stet
or a single Telecom cannot survive on a Telecommunications market which
includes transcontinental US giants and at least three Stets or Telecoms have
to combine together. Hence the necessity for their privatisation - so that they
can join together with other firms and create at least a continent-wide group. Likewise
for the banks, for industries and for States themselves.
The Two Dimensional State
Together with the liberalisation of the market
the dominant ideology also demands the slimming-down of the national state. There
is talk of a 'lean state' to depict a state with little power and few
functions; which watches over free competition and guarantees that there is
equal opportunity for everyone. But here too, just as with the process of
concentration of companies, the dominant ideology demands the disengagement of
the national state not because - as some theoreticians of localism imagine - it
is necessary to have a world of free states on a free market, but because the
concentration and centralisation of capital has reached such a level that
national states are no longer capable of coherently carrying out their basic
tasks. If the great monopoly groupings are to remain competitive on the world
market they have to be able to participate in the division of financial
revenues. This in turn means that the State these monopolies take as their
reference point must have the capacity to manage the main macro-economic
variables efficiently and sensibly, in particular the money supply. A state
with low currency reserves is incapable of confronting the shock waves of
international speculation to which the whole economy is exposed. In 1987 a US
financier, Andy Krieger, made huge gains at the expense of the New Zealand
Central Bank when he openly sold the country's entire currency on the currency
options market. Now, if you consider that Krieger could move only 700 million
dollars of the $1.3bn which are daily moved on the international financial
markets it is easy to appreciate that in a globalised economy, dominated by
large-scale finance capital, it is not the state as such which no longer has
reason to exist but the smaller states which can no longer survive. Thus, the
process of disengagement of national states that we are currently witnessing is
not the prelude to a weakening of the state, but rather signals a different
kind of construct by virtue of the existence of currency zones of at least
continental dimensions.
The outcome is a lightweight and decentralised
state at national level but one which is powerful and highly centralised at
continental level: it is the state of the great transnational monopoly groups.
New Imperialist Balance of
Power
After the collapse of the Berlin Wall, which
heralded that of the entire Soviet Empire, bourgeois propaganda was full of
hymns of praise announcing the dawn of a new era. There was to be no more war
because the last war had been won; no more misery because, liberated from the
evil world of communism, the flower of prosperity would bloom everywhere;
neither would there be dictatorship because capitalism is synonymous with
freedom. Someone in the USA actually talked about "the end of
history".1 Predictably, these expectations ended in disappointment. Wars
continued; as always freedom and prosperity remained the exclusive preserve of
the bourgeoisie and most important of all, inter-imperialist conflicts did not
cease.
Despite being a bare-faced lie, bourgeois
propaganda has not let up. Today the eulogists maintain that economic globalisation
will bring the end of warfare and of the state; someone thinks that if there
are still wars in the near future then these will be clashes between different
civilisations and cultures but no longer a struggle over material interests. 2
According to this new orthodoxy once the transformation of the big monopoly
groupings into transnational configurations is complete the big multinationals
will no longer have an identifiable national basis. Business interests will
stretch far and wide, forming part of a single tapestry where every thread is
interwoven and which it will be in everyone's interests to keep intact.
This fascinating idea is in sharp contrast with
reality. As we have seen, in reality the success of a monopoly group demands
some basic prerequisites - that it has:
a) at least a continental scope;
b) the capacity to organise in various parts of
the world to achieve the best combination of productivity/labour costs;
c) the capacity to compensate for a low rate of
profit with the realisation of a corresponding extra-profit;
d) a secure area under its hegemony capable of
absorbing a given quota of production.
Now, if we reflect carefully here it is clear
that every one of these conditions implies the existence of a solid basis of
reference. In particular, the realisation of an extra-profit necessitates a
currency which is able to battle on the international market for the division
of the financial returns, especially as the constant decline in the average
rate of profit - as we have already seen - will continue to increase the number
and size of capitals which are unable to find adequate returns from direct
investment in production. Thus the struggle for the parasitic appropriation of
surplus value will become increasingly fierce and the global village is
destined to become smaller and smaller for the growing number of vampires who
inhabit it. Already, even though only a single superpower remains on the scene,
the struggle to conquer positions of hegemony is disseminating terror and death
in every corner of the world. From the Caucasus to Afghanistan; from the Urals
to the Balkans; in the Middle East; throughout the continent of Africa, in
Latin America, there is not a single strip of ground which is not tormented by
war generated by the conflict of interests between the various factions of
imperialism. Certainly we are a long way from the formation of imperialist
blocs equivalent to that of the United States - or, more precisely, heading a
currency area equivalent to the dollar - but what else is the formation of a
single European currency aimed at? Or the huge German investments in Russia? Or
Japanese expansion in South-east Asia? On the one hand Europe, particularly
Germany, and on the other hand Japan, are at a cross roads: either they combine
with others to face up to the dollar bloc, which by now includes practically
the whole of continental America, or they are condemned to submit to American
supremacy which in the last instance means ceding a growing proportion of
surplus value to the dollar zone and running the risk of seeing first the
decline and eventually the economic and financial collapse of their own area.
In fact Germany has already set out down this
road. The influence of the D-mark is now extended throughout Eastern Europe
and, even if in juxtaposition with the dollar, throughout much of the Balkans
as well. In addition Holland, Belgium, Denmark, Austria and Sweden are
effectually in the area of the mark. Its influence has also increased in Iran
and in some areas of Africa but all this is not enough. It is up against a
market, an army and a state which for up to a century has alone had all of
this. It would need the entire European community to constitute a single
currency area before there could be an equal balance of forces and even then
the situation might not change. The destiny of the world also depends on the
development of the crisis in Russia: whether the outcome will be something
capable of playing its own role or whether the Russian state will have been so
reduced that it will be able to do nothing else but align with someone stronger
- Japan or China. In fact only the inaccurate general statistics of the IMF can
pass off what is happening in China as a massive process of economic
development in contrast with the rest of the world. In reality China can be
seen as an Asian equivalent of Russia: a confused mess of contradictions ready
to explode at the first whisper of rebellion.
It is difficult to predict whether this
complicated puzzle will work itself out. However, there are powerful economic
impulses towards the formation of at least another two big currency zones
beyond that of the dollar. Around these there are signs of at least as many
again state-continent alliances, even transcontinental, struggling for control
over the instruments used to extort financial returns. Whoever remains small or
doesn't grow large enough is destined to be crushed. Only by leaving aside
these impulses, or rather by completely hypothetically setting aside the
inherent contradictions of capitalism's accumulation process, can a world
without conflict be imagined. The very tendency towards the formation of new
currency zones is also propelling the strongest economic areas to separate from
the weakest. This impulse cuts across national states and in some cases fosters
tensions which can even lead to their break up (as in ex-Yugoslavia) and/or to
interimperialist wars so divisive and devastating that the impulse towards
continental integration is thwarted.
From this examination it is sufficently clear that
the facts themselves do not show that the prediction of war as the only
bourgeois solution to the crisis is either mistaken or has been superseded. On
the one hand the current process of capitalist restructuring has led to a
gigantic devaluation of labour power, reducing the fall in the rate of profit
at the same time as promoting the growth of financial income. On the other
hand, although the original contradictions still remain the crisis has become
more uniform on a planetary level and has now reached such a depth that it is
increasingly difficult for it to be managed by the usual financial and economic
instruments: capital has no alternative but to have more and more recourse to
destructive violence.
Thus not even the absence of comparable power
blocs struggling against each other removes the prospect of war. The prospect
now is of so-called low intensity wars, of local conflicts whether tribal or
religious, but always inter-imperialist. A sort of permanent war, an immense
black hole of self-destruction in which a growing number of people, things and
bits of civilisation are sucked up until there is total barbarism.
Conclusion
A proletariat imprisoned by the trade union
logic of the possibility of reconciling the interests of capital and the
working class, corrupted by Stalinism and permeated - via the existence of a
solid workers' aristocracy - by petty bourgeois life-styles, is consequently
incapable of even minimally opposing capitalist restructuring. Yet the signs of
a profound change in the relationship between classes are daily becoming
clearer.
During the upswing in the current cycle of
accumulation the elevated rate of profit favoured the formation of a workers'
aristocracy in the capitalist metropoles. At the same time the middle class
grew along with a petty bourgeois life-style which - at least in the
metropolitan countries - was also adopted by the vast majority of the
proletariat and ensured the stability of the system. Now, however, the same
motive force which is forcing the permanent devaluation of labour power and
leading to increased parasitic appropriation is imposing a constant reduction
in the portion of surplus value destined for the petty bourgeoisie and the
workers' aristocracy. Further, information technology has also pervaded office
work and the professions and made numerous activities linked to distribution
redundant. In the field of commerce it is the small and medium sized enterprise
which is being made obsolete, part of the process of break-up and
reconstitution of social classes which prevails world-wide and which is leading
to the proletarianisation of society. Thus we see large sections of the petty
bourgeoisie following radical calls from conservative quarters who are vainly
trying to halt this process (regionalism, secessionism, Leaguism3). The
possibility of their playing a key role in an openly reactionary movement,
especially if the crisis suddenly gets worse, cannot be ruled out. Nevertheless,
the process of proletarianisation together with the standardisation of methods
of exploitation also provide the most favourable objective conditions for the
formation of a strong internationalist communist force which can act as a
secure reference point for the working class and a political base for at least
a part of the proletariat.
The problem we are faced with is to understand
how a dispersed vanguard such as ours can contribute to the rebuilding of the
international revolutionary party out of the shifting sands which surround it. Sooner
or later the growing weight of exploitation is going to move the proletariat.
Footnotes
1 Francis Fukayama, who soon changed his mind..
2 Samuel P Huntington..
3 The term is from the Northern League - led by
Umberto Bossi - who is demanding the secession of relatively rich northern
Italy from the south.